what is paroxetine prescribed for metformin 500 mg gpo hoeveel mg propranolol viagra mexico generico ponstel results forum 20mg prednisone euphoria chloramphenicol online overnight achat cialis 10 mg amoxil capsule 250mg buy medrol singapore lasix 80 mg gouttes cialis generic order atacand 16 mg effets secondaires buy liv 52 inhaler canada what is doxazosin pills used for lamisil cream for thrush prednisone 10mg buy buy retin a cream 0.05 buying metformin use aciclovir coupon online clomid cost 100mg overnight generic cheap diclofenac 500mg metformin enough cheap price valtrex 100mg. vardenafil levitra where is crestor manufacturer lisinopril 2 5 mg fish cycline forte acne cialis online.ca much does plan b generic cost walgreens amoxil suspension shelf life when did generic femara become available cialis 18 mg ayurvedic viagra online indocin cost cheapest optimmune ointment xenical 120 mg capsulas duras champix cost ireland american levitra professional reglan prescription information what does topamax pill look like kamagra effervescente 100 mg proscar online forum where to buy synthetic drugs online can we trust gasex online azithromycin diarrhea how long pastillas redustat como se toman amoxil bd 500mg what is pravachol 40 mg what is cephalexin 500mg used for in humans synthroid without rx wellbutrin 300mg online pharmacy accutane secure site cialis 20mg ellily amaryl echeck dilantin online canadian 250mg amoxil cheapest atacand in the uk lexapro 5 mg breastfeeding efficacite cialis 20mg brand lamictal for sale caratteristiche cialis 20 mg brand name glucotrol xl online buy zovirax 5 ointment cap augmentin 625mg order buspar 5mg can you get high from codeine cough syrup viagra 25 mg france lidocaine gel buy billig finax online kaufen ciprofloxacin cipro generic prevacid where can i buy health canada altace amantadine fast usa buy cheap lexapro no prescription cialis preis 5 mg prandin 100mg tablet cordarone new zealand order zoloft cod india generic drugs free can you buy lotrisone cream affected retino-a cream 0,025 usa cvs prices purchase paxil 40 mg viagra japan buy what is cleocin ovules used to treat propranolol hcl 80 mg celebrex canada online land for sale alligator creek united states online pharamcy zoloft 500mg generic cipro 500 mg doxycycline 100 mg jerawat viagra professional online prednisone 60 mg cost cialis 10mg coupon abilify drug information betnovate ointment 0.1 used xenical 120 mg gunanya toprol generic side effects can you buy singulair over the counter asthma lexapro liver disorder advair diskus buy online australia dubai generic viagra mgs of cialis how much does zetia cost at walmart indian generics online cleocin painkillers no prescription zovirax 400 mg tabletas buy effexor online canada no prescription aleve discount order merck propecia cytotec 200 mg tablet zaditor costco danazol ordering no prescription long term side effects of zantac nizoral fda approved to buy without prescription reminyl uk buy generic lexapro order increasing metabolism foods what is the dosage for benadryl allergy cialis 10 mg efficient car salesman drug test priligy 30 mg filmtabletten order silagra india can you order aciphex generic name for cipro iv brand brand advair diskus for sale what is benfotiamine made of viagra 100mg hinta order viagra without rx online better than plendil generic womens viagra xenical oral buy cipro medicine used for vbuy viagra online sale cialis sublingual prednisone 20 mg tabletas can you buy hyzaar canadian pharmacy lexapro 10 mg kullanimi purchasing elavil online celebrex goes generic clomid pills uk clomid 100mg fertility celebrex dosage 100mg buy canada no prescription for levothroid lexapro patient assistance program form viagra prescription only approved pharmacy lotrisone generic buy side effects of augmentin in adults brand viagra capsules cheap glucophage valtrex online canada buy cardura prescription online google cheap viagra lexapro 10mg lundbeck which uk site to buy levlen viagra 100 mg duracion pariet drugs use generic lasix pills cefixime usa celexa from canadian pharmacy best site get elavil alli orlistat weight loss capsules lexapro 10mg cena cheapest propecia canada low cost overnight eurax order viagra overnight cardizem lawsuit arimidex discount medications buy cheap adderall online uk non prescription asacol pharmacy amoxicillin 500mg capsules used minocycline dosage too high trustworthy generic viagra can you order phenergan canadian online pharmacy alphagan metformin prescription information uk xalatan costco lasix furosemide 20 mg how many baclofen pills to get high cheap dapoxetine online where to buy cheap generic clomid buy zithromax azithromycin buy bupron sr online india paroxetine 10 mg amoxil 500 mg cost azulfidine uk next day delivery purchasing cytotec online uk mobic brands india viagra supplies australia pms hydrochlorothiazide 25 mg augmentin generic liquid why has fincar been discontinued aspirin price germany what does the pill trazodone do half price aygestin buy tricorn hat online erythromycin 500mg tablets brand levitra medication where to buy actos drugs com generic levitra plus for sale on line cialis generic 40mg. cheap kamagra uk jelly 100mg cipro 500 mg diarrhea buy adderall online uk no prescription acticin generic for what infections is cipro used for durata viagra 100mg generic zenegra uk paypal viagra generica farmacia lynoral tablets uses price of depakote without insurance 0.05 mg of synthroid buy nolvadex lexapro drug schedule purim canada head office levitra 20mg srbija buy zovirax zovirax accutane long term depression lexapro 20 mg tablets lexapro 10 mg medication discount lexapro online fastest atorlip-20 uk delivery buy pulmicort flexhaler 400 mg celebrex augmentin 875 mg price paypal excepted generic cialis lisinopril tablet 10mg can i get diflucan at planned parenthood generic cialis purchase cialis 5 y 20 mg bula do prednisona cialis 5mg fta 28 lisinopril 20 mg reviews how long after accutane pregnancy generic indian cialis how to get glyset in australia best price lipitor 10 mg increasing milk supply at 3 months zaditor non perscription countries power viagra 8 200mg yagara how to buy buy isoniazid mexican pharmacies is it legal to buy viagra online in canada can fucidin cream be used for eczema candian pharmacy seroquel no rx pilex low dose birth control exelon patch cost cvs viagra 50 vai 100 mg acquisto diamox sicuro online is it illegal to order generic elavil viagra levitra cialis mycoxafloppin wikipedia diflucan 50 mg posologie pastile cialis 20 mg how to buy betapace viagra competitors extra sex and the city generic name for lotensin hct calan quality buy cheap typical dosage valtrex herpes outbreak hydrochlorothiazide 25 mg edema obat metformin 500 mg what is neurontin used for and what are the side effects generic viagra buy flomax no prrescription propecia pills what promethazine tablets price triamterene 37.5 mg hctz 25mg sinequan without insurance cheap meds viagra meloxicam for cats dose vasodilan online coupon code what gift cards can i buy with paypal cytotec pills online in the usa generic yasmin switzerland store zanaflex cheap generic wellbutrin overdose 600 mg how to by cialis super active online buy olanzapine paypal cialis online euroclinix 500mg of metformin nexium 40 mg tablets best place to buy ditropan in usa generic cialis 40mg metformin 500 mg tabletki viagra wholesale canada blopress lowest price online carafate medication side effects generico de valtrex 500 kopen cialis 40mg xenical meridia suhagra 50 side effects strattera price 40mg what does glucophage do vardenafil generico colombia prescription norvasc praziquantel for dogs best price generic aceon usa pharmacy nizoral dandruff shampoo 100ml review tegretol online in us viagra online hongkong side effects of saw palmetto tamoxifen 10 mg indian generics online decadron augmentin 250 mg tablets birth control shot depo provera reviews levitra pills cialis generyczny 20 mg biaxin over counter priligy user review ralista shoppers drug mart xenical 120 mg leaflet zithromax paypal what are the side effects of cephalexin in dogs permethrin cream otc canada doxycycline 500mg chlamydia adipex and topamax for weight loss reviews 25mg of phenergan 500 mg metformin daily how to by lozol online nexium 40 mg contraindicaciones taking 40 mg lexapro can you get high from trazodone drugs lasix water pill and weight loss side effects of hydrochlorothiazide in women ginseng capsules review augmentin online ireland generic prozac manufacturers cheapest 2.5 mg cialis can you buy things on itunes with paypal retin a 0.1 cream side effects buy propranolol hydrochloride cabgolin free shipping what does the drug depakote treat tretinoin cream 0.1 price what is keflex used to treat medicamento propranolol 40 mg online pharmacy levothroid where to buy cheap generic chloramphenicol kamagra 150 mg buy cheap 200mg cialis telmisartan and hydrochlorothiazide tablets elimite online order buy aristocort online pharmacy sumycin pharmacy hydrochlorothiazide 5 mg order doxycycline usa viagra 2.5mg preisvergleich viagra 50 mg clomid 50 mg eisprong much generic propecia lipothin overnight delivery tinidazole 10 mg cost best generic dapoxetine sites erection packs 11 drugs online zoloft 150 mg reviews vasotec dosage hypertension long time side effects protonix cialis 800mg china erythromycin bp 250mg fastest online viagra top 10 online erexin-v sites 90 wellbutrin xl 300mg methotrexate monitoring protocol propranolol online kaufen cialis generico inghilterra cheap leukeran pills 400mg zovirax what are normal thyroxine levels doxycycline 100 mg 50 tabs acai looking for levitra online buy buy viagra vs cialis vs levitra cheap elavil usa promethazine and codeine cough syrup ingredients does gnc sell water pills amaryl rx can you buy cialis soft in ireland prescription big discounts liposafe overnight pharmacy zithromax liquid buy zoloft 100 mg compresse canada drugs zebeta with prescription buy buspar uk existe cialis generico buy hyzaar online reviews webmd generic viagra buy amaryllis bulbs nyc viagra generics herbal medrol dose pack side effects anxiety cialis super active tablets online prescription mobic is for meloxicam generic zoloft diarrhea tienchi ginseng tablets how to take crestor medication propecia msd online aleve suppositories buy cipro buy canada overnight pharmacy cialis soft metformin atid 500mg pictures of synthroid pills buy alesse overnight viagra sildenafil 50mg generic valtrex cipla discount canadian pharmacy isoniazid cialis generic uk propecia generic 5mg cost of aspirin to nhs zithromax z-pak cheap american prazosin kamagra buy cheap lotrisone 100 online canadian viagra clomiphene side effects xenical ordinare online advantages disadvantages sublingual drugs 700mg citalopram iverdose propranolol 20 mg ansiedade no prescription cialis usa generic augmentin es 600 viagra buy forum best drugstore mascara of 2012 prednisone 10 mg tablets generic viagra sale how to buy antibiotics online with no prescription forzest no prescription reviews where could i buy effexor without prescription amoxil dosage mg clomid online chemist nexium mups 40mg levitra 10 mg uso clomid medicine children prinivil from usa pharmacy packungsbeilage cialis 5mg is lexapro better than celexa for anxiety buying levitra fucidin cream 2 side effects motilium generic equivalent albendazole 100mg buy nexium esomeprazole 20 mg doxycycline side effects vivid dreams buy bactroban australia nexium 40 mg kaufen order cutotec online in usa buy unisom mg online lithium no prescription canada costco kirkland benadryl is zantac better for you than prilosec augmentin susp 400 mg metformin 1000 mg makedonija 10mg of nolvadex 20mg lexapro reviews viagra soft pills sweat zithromax 1000 mg baclofen online canada buy viagra zenegra to buy micronase in uk nexium 20 mg interactions low cost overnight luvox kamagra cheap apcalis sx pill shortage fastest dulcolax uk delivery extendaquin drug schedule online viagra ireland how to use duetact low cost tofranil viagra professional capsules rabeprazole maximum daily dose best site to buy mevacor rx strattera 40 mg can i go to a minute clinic for viagra generic viagra denmark dapoxetine buy us cialis online srbija phenergan 1 mg diclofenac user reviews generic finast us aricept 5mg tablet dramamine over the counter walgreens lisinopril 2.5 mg hypertension levitra 10 mg costi kamagra oral jelly 100mg paypal buy viagra over the counter generic cost of prednisolone acetate ophthalmic suspension buy benemid in ireland over the counter drugs similar to topamax 80 mg cialis reviews ibuprofen alcohol hangover uk version of isoptin ventolin from australia order cipro prescription cialis 100 mg generic paypal cheap viagra prescription ditropan renagel prices at costco editus pharmacie kirchberg buy kamagra brisbane viagra generic doses acheter coumadin pas cher online cialis fake
Home MLB Network / Extra Innings Opening Statement: Stephen F. Ross on DirecTV Deal

Like Shoot to Thrill - An AC/DC Tribute on Facebook!

An authentic tribute of AC/DC that covers the best of the Bon Scott era and the best of Brian Johnson's material

Who's Online?

We have 399 guests online

Atom RSS

Opening Statement: Stephen F. Ross on DirecTV Deal Print
User Rating: / 10
PoorBest 
Written by Stephen F. Ross   
Tuesday, 27 March 2007 04:32
RESTORING THE MARKET FOR OUT-OF-MARKET BASEBALL
Testimony of Professor Stephen F. Ross
Director, Penn State Institute for Sports Law, Policy and Research
The Pennsylvania State University
Before the
Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation
March 27, 2007
 
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:
 
          It is an honor and privilege to be invited to join a panel of industry leaders to offer an independent view, based on over two decades of scholarship and teaching concerning sports and competition policy, in discussing the impediments to the free flow of interstate commerce as millions of Americans seek ways to take advantage of technological advances to watch non-local Major League Baseball games in their homes.
 
General Thoughts on Exclusive Dealing
 
          The issue before the Committee today is whether the exclusive dealing arrangement between Major League Baseball (MLB) and DirecTV, whereby DirecTV becomes the only source for out-of-market games not shown on national networks, is in the public interest.  As the Supreme Court has recognized,1 exclusive dealing arrangements are both legitimate and indeed can have pro-competitive effects.  In traditional markets where consumers have free access to retail markets, the Court has declared that, as a matter of antitrust law (in my view, this reasoning also applies to sound regulatory policy), these arrangements should only be questioned when there is a serious risk that they will foreclose access to supply or outlet by other firms.2  Thus, an agreement by Sears to exclusively sell Levi’s blue jeans is unlikely to harm consumers; there are ample other retail outlets for Levi’s rivals, and ample other jean manufacturers for Sears’ competitors.  If there are efficiencies in exclusivity, the likely market response is for Lee to reach an exclusive deal with Macy’s, etc.   Consumers unhappy with Sears’ selection are only harmed to the extent they have to walk across the shopping mall.
 
Harm to baseball fans
 
          In contrast, baseball fans face significant harm because of various pre-existing agreements as well as the recently announced exclusive MLB/DirecTV deal.   Those who have other reasons to prefer DishNetwork or cable must either forego quality telecasts of out-of-market baseball games,3 or suffer exploitation by subscribing to multiple multi-channel video distribution platforms that require the purchase of duplicate programming and unnecessary equipment.  The exclusive deal reinforces the harm that already befalls the millions of Americans who do not live within the local media market of their favorite team, because of a horizontal market division agreement entered into by MLB owners that, in the context of football, has been illegal for over 50 years.4  There is no public interest justification in forcing consumers to purchase a distribution platform that is inferior for their needs, or duplicate platforms, just to watch their favorite teams.  These consumers include:
 
  • Residents in areas with heavy thunderstorm activity (such as Florida) who prefer cable because of concerns about weather-related interference with important sports broadcasts
  • Residents of local markets (like metropolitan Philadelphia and southern New Jersey) who are fans of local basketball and hockey teams but out-of-market baseball teams, and would under planned agreements be required to subscribe to cable for some teams and satellite for others
  • Virtually all residents of states without a local team (like Alaska, Hawaii, or Nevada) or states with many retirees from other states (like Florida, California, or Arizona): there is no reason that the only way they can watch games of their favorite teams is to acquire a single product, MLB ExtraInningsTM,  from a single retailer, DirecTV
  • Consumers in multi-residence dwellings who are not allowed to select their preferred retailer, and where the landlord, homeowners’ association, or other decision-maker is insufficiently interested in baseball to switch to DirecTV
 
(Select Read More to see the rest of Ross' opening statement)
 
Restraints on Interstate Commerce: Horizontal Market Division
 
          To be clear, the agreement that sparked this hearing did not arise from the free market.  First, there is the horizontal market division by MLB owners.  Under the common law, the home team owns a property right in the radio and television rights to baseball games.5  However, the MLB owners have agreed to significant limitations on these common law rights.  Each club will only broadcast games in its assigned geographic territory, licensing the visiting club for the purpose of broadcasting games in its own home territory, and assigning to MLB the exclusive right to sell games not only to free-to-air networks (a right protected by the Sports Broadcasting Act) but most significantly the exclusive right to sell non-network games to satellite or cable only through MLB ExtraInningsTM (which is not exempt from antitrust scrutiny). 
 
          Were it not for this web of agreements, the MLB/DirecTV deal would raise few problems for consumers.  Those interested in the convenience of a single package of all out-of-market games could purchase ExtraInningsTM from DirecTV.  A Los Angeles Dodgers fan outside southern California, or someone who simply enjoyed the final years of play-by-play from hall-of-famer Vin Scully, would likely find it possible to purchase Dodger telecasts, acquired from the Dodgers by DirecTV, DishNetwork, or the local cable company.  Other intermediaries might offer a syndicate of games in competition with ExtraInningsTM.
 
          Antitrust precedents suggest that the MLB agreements are anti-competitive and ought to be illegal.  In United States v. National Football League,6 a very sophisticated district court decision that presaged by 30 years the antitrust analysis of broadcast restraints later adopted by the Supreme Court,7 the court noted that sports leagues had a unique interest in promoting competitive balance among member teams so that, to the extent that a rival team’s out-of-market telecast would significantly harm live attendance, the league could agree to prevent this.  However, the court rejected the NFL’s effort to bar out-of-market telecasts that simply competed with the home team’s telecast of road games: the only effect there was to limit output and raise rights fees for the home team, a result that was not legitimate or pro-competitive.  As later courts have recognized,8 leagues can adequately protect competitive balance with regard to television rights sales by revenue sharing, rather than output limits. 
 
          The courts have also recognized, in antitrust litigation, that broad licenses awarded by competing copyright holders through intermediaries can be pro-competitive, when these are non-exclusive licenses.  Thus, the Supreme Court rejected a lower court holding that Broadcast Music and ASCAP violated the Sherman Act by offering a blanket license for the vast majority of copyrighted songs.9 On remand, the court of appeals upheld the legality of the arrangement, but only after finding that potential licensees had real alternative ways of acquiring rights.10  This was because the Justice Department had challenged, many years ago, the agreement among almost all the nation’s songwriters to grant exclusive licenses to BMI or ASCAP – grants akin to the out-of-market assignments that individual team owners have made to DirecTV -- and the parties by consent decree had agreed to limit the license to a non-exclusive grant.11
 
          It is bad enough that these agreements meet the “hallmark” definition of unreasonable restraints of trade, by increasing price, reducing output, and rendering output unresponsive to consumer demand.12  In fact, these agreements are even more inefficient and anti-competitive than would be the case if all rights to all games were assigned to a single entity.  Because the additional costs of showing games to out-of-market fans is virtually zero, such an entity would likely sell, in addition to local rights and ExtraInningsTM, other packages to other consumers.  For example, there are surely many fans who would pay, on a per game or per team basis, for out-of-market games.  These are not authorized now, not because the sale would not be profitable, but because the MLB owners can not agree on how to divide the profits.13
 
Insufficient competition in multi-channel video distribution
 
          An analysis of the economics of rights sales for out-of-market games demonstrates that the current scheme would be implausible except for two additional deviations from the free market: (1) insufficient competition between DirecTV, DishNetwork, and cable permits excess profits from consumers of “basic premium” programming; (2) by tying the sale of ExtraInningsTM to its “Choice” package, DirecTV is able to increase its excess profits and the agreement in question reflects a sharing of those increased excess profits between DirecTV and Major League Baseball.
 
          Although there are important differences in the economics of English football and North American sports, on both sides of the Atlantic we see leagues that offer entertainment products with no reasonable substitutes selling broadcast rights to a major programmer in return for a large, fixed sum of money.  Policy questions about exclusive agreements for prime sports programming have also arisen in the United Kingdom, and have been insightfully analyzed in a working paper widely distributed among sports economists.14  Economists David Harbord and Marco Ottaviani detail the profit-maximizing strategy for the various market participants.  First, they note that leagues are likely to sell rights for a fixed rather than per-subscriber fee.  A fixed fee avoids the problem of the rights-purchaser tacking on its own excess profits charge to that imposed by the league.15  Because MLB doesn’t know precisely how many fans will subscribe to ExtraInningsTM, or how effectively DirecTV will market the product, it has an even greater incentive to sell for fixed fees, as the rights-purchaser is better able to accept the risk of marketing the product effectively during the course of the contract.  If the rights purchaser is effective in maximizing revenues from resale and advertising, results of which are usually reported in the trade press, the league can profit from the rights purchaser’s success to secure even higher rights fees for the next contract.  (For example, the NFL’s first network contract with CBS gave each owner $300,000/yr.  Three years later, the second contract gave each owner $1 million/yr.)
 
          Next, Harbord & Ottaviani explain why a rights-purchaser, having paid a lump-sum to obtain rights for which there was no substitute, would want to re-sell rights on a per-subscriber basis to its cable and satellite rivals.  Ordinarily, they observe, by re-selling to rivals, the rights purchaser increases the marginal operating costs for its rivals at the same time it fetches additional revenue.  This “makes reselling more profitable for the firm which acquires the rights, and hence more likely to occur.”16  Re-selling on a per-subscriber basis results in higher rights fees (because the league can capture a portion of the additional profit to be obtained from reselling on a per-subscriber basis) and maximizes output (more people subscribe).
 
          Applied to American baseball, Harbord & Ottaviani’s analysis suggests that DirecTV would find it profitable to resell ExtraInnings to cable networks and Dish Network, and that MLB would share in this profit through a higher lump-sum fee for the exclusive rights to out-of-market baseball games.  So why have DirecTV and MLB done the opposite?  We can infer from the parties’ preference for an exclusive deal that DirecTV is willing to forego this opportunity, and indeed pay MLB more than the total amount that MLB might reasonably expect to receive from sales of ExtraInnings through various retail outlets.  This is because DirecTV would prefer to force some out-of-market baseball fans to switch their patronage to DirecTV, rather than obtain all the revenue from out-of-market fans, regardless of which “retailer” these fans patronize.  DirecTV’s ability to obtain more revenue from those fans that remain with or switch to DirecTV than it could by charging the full monopoly price for ExtraInningsTM to all out-of-market fans is most likely due to their ability to obtain even greater super-competitive profits from those that switch.
 
     Suppose one million fans would be willing to subscribe to ExtraInningsTM at $160 per season, but that 200,000 of these will not patronize DirecTV (perhaps they fear thunderstorms, prefer programming available only on cable, can’t afford two systems in areas where local cable is unavailable, don’t have a clear south-facing view on their property, must use the system subscribed by the landlord, etc.).  That’s $32 million in lost revenue.  The exclusive deal means that DirecTV plans on making this up by obtaining new customers from cable or DishNetwork.  If 300,000 ExtraInnings customers switch to DirecTV’s Choice package (at $480/yr) + ExtraInningsTM, that’s an additional $144 million in revenue (from Choice, not MLB games, which these fans were already purchasing via cable or DishNetwork).  If DirecTV’s operational and programming costs in servicing the new customers was not well below $144 million, this scheme wouldn’t be profitable.  Only the excess profits on the Choice package – which baseball fans are required to purchase as a condition of subscribing to ExtraInningsTM, – is what allows DirecTV to profitably enter into an exclusive deal.
 
    One other explanation is theoretically possible – that there are huge cost-saving efficiencies from an exclusive dealing arrangement.  However, no one has, to date, seriously made this claim on behalf of MLB or DirecTV.
 
Summary of economic analysis

    The foregoing analysis suggests that the MLB/DirecTV exclusive deal reflects the ability of these sellers to exploit baseball fans because of the lack of any substitute products, and thus impose a monopoly price and significantly reduce output.  Out-of-market games will henceforth only be available on DirecTV, presumably at the monopoly price.  The absence of alternative means of obtaining out-of-market games means millions of consumers will pay more.  But it also means that output is substantially reduced, because of foregone purchases (all of which would be considerably above the marginal cost of production) from (i) expatriate fans of one particular team willing to pay a lower price to watch their favorite team but unwilling to pay for the ExtraInnings package; (ii) avid fans who have other preferential reasons to prefer to continue to subscribe to cable or Dish Network; (iii) marginal customers of satellite programming, who otherwise prefer DirecTV’s programming but decline to pay the “basic premium” price charged by DirecTV because it reflects in part the need to share profits with MLB.  This is bad public policy.
 
Ways that legislation can protect consumers
 
    There are a number of ways that existing or potential legislation could protect baseball fans against exploitation by inefficient and anti-competitive broadcast agreements:
 
  • Existing antitrust laws could be used to invalidate these unreasonable restraints of trade.
  • Specific antitrust legislation could be enacted to facilitate this result.
  • Regulatory legislation could minimize the excess profits that satellite and cable providers enjoy from their “basic premium” packages, or could directly prohibit the bundling essential to the exclusivity scheme by requiring “a la carte” pricing.
  • Strategic legislation could also be introduced by leading members of this committee as a means of facilitating voluntary pro-consumer compliance by industry.

Existing antitrust enforcement
 
    As detailed below, even vigorous enforcement of the antitrust laws by the Justice Department would face significant obstacles to quick resolution in time to protect sports fans.  Unfortunately, the record of the current Antitrust Division leadership does not lead to a confident prediction of such enforcement.  The obstacles to private litigation to effectively protect consumers are even greater.  For these reasons, reliance on existing law is unlikely to constitute an adequate public policy response by this Congress. 
 
    A government enforcement action should be able to rely on the precedents discussed above to establish that the horizontal restraint among MLB clubs is an unreasonable restraint of trade.  The exclusive broadcast territories are neither necessary to promote competitive balance among member teams nor to prevent any efficiency-deterring free riding. The only way in which a club’s sale of their games into another geographic market could harm competitive balance would be if the additional revenue generated from these out-of-market rights fees would enable the teams to acquire enough talent to enable them to dominate the league. This scenario is implausible for a number of reasons. There is no evidence that these fees would be significant enough to affect competitive balance. More important, there is no reason why the leagues could not share these revenues, as Major League Baseball has with teams whose games are carried nationwide via locally-based superstations.
 
    Nor can the leagues, in this context, sensibly claim that the restraint is an intra-firm restraint among the “single entity” of the league, rather than the horizontal agreement among independent clubs.  Because of the economics of rights sales, a single firm would sell all rights in all games that are going to be televised to the highest bidder, who could then re-sell the games to consumers in a price discriminating manner designed to yield the greatest revenue (noting again that the marginal costs of selling a game once it is being televised is virtually zero).  The ExtraInnings package is the only way that out-of-market fans can get games, not because this is DirecTV’s preference, but because it is the choice of the majority of MLB clubs.  DirecTV would clearly be better off if it could price discriminate by selling the ExtraInnings package to those with a demand for over 1,000 baseball games, and selling a smaller package of games (or even individual games on a pay-per-view basis) to its subscribers unwilling to pay for ExtraInnings.  Rather, individual games are unavailable to out-of-market fans, despite the potential for profitable sales, because transactions costs prevent owners from agreeing on how to divide the spoils.  As a result, the interest of the league-as-a-whole in maximizing revenues from television sales is subordinated to the interests of individual teams in protecting their own local broadcast rights and preventing rivals from attaining a competitive advantage from more successful out-of-market rights sales.  This is not the “unity of interest” that the Supreme Court has required to exclude agreements among formally separate entities from review under section 1 of the Sherman Act.17
 
    Existing precedents with regard to tying arrangements might also support a claim that DirecTV’s practice of bundling ExtraInningsTM with its $40/mo. Choice package is also unreasonable.  However, there are several serious obstacles to successful government prosecution of such a lawsuit.  First, MLB could claim that the judicially-created baseball exemption applies to broadcast restraints.  Although good arguments can be made that the exemption does not apply,18 the result is ultimately an uncertain question likely to require ultimate resolution, after years of litigation, by the Supreme Court.  Second, although DirecTV’s bundling practices would appear to be unreasonable under existing precedents,19these precedents have come under criticism by commentators20 and justices.21  Moreover, current regulation of cable and satellite practices by the FCC might be held to preclude antitrust scrutiny of this behavior. 
 
    Private enforcement is even more problematic.  The obstacles stated above pose major litigation risks that would deter private antitrust attorneys from commencing expensive litigation.  Because the proposed exclusive deal is prospective, treble damage relief (and accompanying attorneys fees funded by the damage award) would not be available for that aspect of the challenge.  My own experience as a public interest advocate has been that private firms are unlikely to view the grant of statutory attorneys fees provided for in the Clayton Act as a sufficient economic incentive to undertake the costs of uncertain litigation.  In addition, private litigation on behalf of consumers who currently patronize DirecTV would have to confront complex issues that would arise in light of the contract-by-adhesion DirecTV requires all customers that provides for disputes to be arbitrated.
 

New antitrust legislation
 
    This Committee could defer to your Judiciary Committee colleagues, who could consider specific legislation that amended the Sports Broadcasting Act to prohibit the sort of bundling or exclusive dealing practices identified in this testimony.  There is a long history of specific legislation enacted by Congress to outlaw specific anti-competitive practices: indeed, the Clayton Act was passed to specifically outlaw tying arrangements arguably illegal under the Sherman Act, over the objections of former President William Howard Taft, who left the White House to accepted a chaired professorship at Yale Law School and wrote a book arguing for the adequacy of the Sherman Act on this and other points.22
 
Regulatory legislation
 
    As Judge Richard Posner famously observed, a “firm that has no market power is unlikely to adopt policies that disserve its consumers; it cannot afford to. And if it blunders and does adopt such a policy, market retribution will be swift.”23  The corollary, of course, is that firms with market power can afford to disserve consumers and market retribution will not be swift. 
 
    Either expressly, or by delegation to the FCC, this Committee could craft legislation that recognizes that market retribution is not swift in either the market for out-of-market baseball games or the market for delivery of multi-channel video distribution.  A variety of regulatory approaches might be considered.  I would be pleased to continue to work with you and your staff if any of these are of particular interest:
 
  • Listed Events Legislation: A variety of other countries have enacted legislation that specifically requires a variety of important sporting events to remain on free-to-air television, for the benefit of millions of consumers.
  • “A La Carte” Pricing: Satellite and cable companies could be prohibited from requiring lengthy subscriptions to their “basic premium” packages as a condition of subscription to high-demand sport programming.  The analysis above suggests that DirecTV would quickly lose its incentive to pay MLB for exclusive rights if cable subscribers could, in a secondary market, acquire DirecTV equipment and then simply subscribe to ExtraInningsTM without having to pay $40/mo. for Choice.
  • Specifically Ban Sports Exclusivity: Unlike general delegations contained in the Sherman Act or the Federal Communications Act, Congress is free to write specific legislation to deal with specific industry problems.  Based on the economic analysis summarized above, the Committee could conclude that copyright holders and their licensees can fully exploit their intellectual property rights by sale and re-sale and there is no legitimate justification (sharing in excess profits from limited retail competition is not legitimate) for exclusive agreements in this area.24
 
Strategic behavior – by Major League Baseball and by the Senate Commerce Committee
 
    Both business and political actors often behave strategically – they act in a way that may or may not further immediate short-run goals in order to achieve long-run objectives.  Although MLB owners are rightly accused of being short-sighted and greedy in some instances, there are many other occasions where MLB owners have decided that the long-term health of the National Pastime is more important.  It is possible that this is one of those occasions: that MLB owners see a strong future in the development of The Baseball Channel, and the exclusive agreement with DirecTV is simply a negotiating strategy to persuade DishNetwork and cable companies to re-sell The Baseball Channel on favorable terms.
 
    If market retribution were swift among cable and satellite programmers, this would not be a problem.  If MLB’s demands were not unreasonable, then so many consumers would shift to DirecTV that rival MVPDs would have to go along.  If MLB’s demands were unreasonable, then DirecTV would lose so much money that it would eventually back out.  However, anyone inside the Beltway is familiar with the lack of swift retribution reflected in the lengthy negotiations that were required before millions of Capital-area baseball fans could obtain Washington Nationals local broadcasts on their stations.  The FCC has already recognized that market retribution is not swift in a number of non-sports contexts involving cable mergers, requiring programmers and distributors to either reach agreement on terms or submit their unresolved disputes to binding commercial arbitration.   
 
    There are a variety of situations where public policy may require government intervention, but where the best solution would be a voluntary agreement among private parties rather than direct legislation.  An excellent example of that technique was recently employed by this Committee, when under Senator McCain’s chairmanship there were explicit overtures to MLB owners and players to agree on new procedures for steroid testing or face federal legislative intervention.  The result was a voluntary deal that is probably superior to anything Congress could have done.25
 
    Likewise, if it appears that the best resolution of this controversy is voluntary agreement among MLB and the various programming distributors, perhaps this Committee could proceed strategically by threatening onerous legislation (barring collective sales of sports broadcasting rights to satellite and cable, mandating a la carte programming, authorizing FCC rate regulation of premium programming, etc.) unless the parties reach a voluntary agreement or agree to submit the matter to binding commercial arbitration.
 
Conclusion
 
    The MLB/DirecTV exclusive deal is not like a facially-similar contract between Sears and Levi’s.  Rather, the deal reflects (1) cartel behavior by MLB clubs in refusing to sell out-of-market rights to their games except via ExtraInningsTM on DirecTV and (2) a willingness of DirecTV to share the excess profits it enjoys from its Choice package with MLB.  Millions of baseball fans who no longer live near their favorite teams are harmed by their inability to watch their teams’ local broadcasts except via ExtraInningsTM, and harmed particularly by being forced to do so via DirecTV.  This Committee has a variety of arrows in its legislative quiver to protect consumers from this sort of exploitation.
 


RESTORING THE MARKET FOR OUT-OF-MARKET BASEBALL
Testimony of Professor Stephen F. Ross
Professor of Law, The Dickinson School of Law
Director, Penn State Institute for Sports Law, Policy and Research
The Pennsylvania State University
Before the
Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation
March 27, 2007
 
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
 
1) Although exclusive dealing agreements with retailers whom consumers can access for free can often be pro-competitive, the MLB/DirecTV deal threatens to harm a wide variety of consumers
 
  • Fans who, for other reasons, are unable or unwilling to switch to DirecTV
  • Fans who would prefer to get out-of-market games other than the entire ExtraInningsTM package
 
2) The agreement exploits significant departures from the free market
 
  • MLB clubs agree to only telecast games in assigned territories, contrary to a 50-year old antitrust precedent
  • MVPDs face insufficient competition, allowing them excess profits for their basic premium service
 
3) Economic analysis shows that ordinarily, DirecTV would want to re-sell ExtraInnings to its cable and satellite rivals at a high per-subscriber charge; the exclusive deal reflects a sharing of additional excess profits DirecTV will obtain by forcing consumers to switch to its Choice or higher premium packages
 
4) Although the conduct is arguably illegal under the antitrust laws, a number of obstacles render litigation inadequate to protect consumers
 
5) Congress could, alternatively, consider:
 
  • Regulatory legislation to outlaw specific sports programming practices that harm consumers
  • Amendments to the Sports Broadcasting Act to specifically outlaw anti-consumer practices
  • “Strategic” legislation onerous to the industry that would facilitate voluntary compliance


1 Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320 (1961).
2 Id. at 334.
3 Standard antitrust analysis properly focuses on whether a product or service faces competition from “reasonable substitutes” that will draw consumers if there is a small but significant increase in price or decrease in quality of the good or service in question.  Courts have generally found that major sports are sufficiently unique in consumers’ hearts – baseball is, after all, the National Pastime – that a small increase in the price of watching a favorite baseball team will not send enough fans to the library or to cricket websites to render the move unprofitable.  See, e.g., National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984) (college football is a market distinct from professional football or other forms of entertainment); International Boxing Club v. United States, 358 U.S. 242 (1959) (championship boxing is a market distinct from non-championship boxing).
 
            Likewise, the issue here concerns quality telecasts to be displayed on television sets of increasing size and clarity.  Although some fans may prefer the convenience of watching webcasts of out-of-market games on their computers, or others are willing to endure the significant reduction in picture quality when subscribing to mlb.com, these webcasts are not the sort of reasonable substitutes for ExtraInningsTM that either antitrust doctrine or public policy ought require.
4 United States v. National Football League, 116 F.Supp. 319 (E.D. Pa. 1953).
5 See, e.g., Pittsburgh Athletic Co. v. KQV Broad. Co., 24 F. Supp. 490 (W.D. Pa. 1938).
6 116 F.Supp. 319 (E.D. Pa. 1953).
7 National Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984).
8 Chicago Professional Sports Ltd. v. National Basketball Ass’n, 961 F.2d 667 (7th Cir. 1992).
9 Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1  (1979).
10 Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc. v. American Soc’y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 620 F.2d 930 (2d Cir. 1980).
11 CBS v. Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 10-11, citing United States v. American Soc’y of Composers, Artists & Publishers, 1940-1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 56,104 (S.D.N.Y. 1941).
12 NCAA, 468 U.S. at 107.
13 There are at least two recent examples of this phenomenon.  In 1992, the English Premier League, having agreed to show 60 of its 380 matches exclusively on the BSkyB satellite, rejected BSkyB’s offer to show 90 matches for a 50% increase in fees.  At about the same time, the National Basketball Association succeeded in strictly limiting the very popular broadcasts of the Chicago Bulls featuring Michael Jordan, despite evidence that Bulls’ broadcasts had minimal effects in other markets, refusing to copy MLB’s practice of taxing superstation revenue.
14 David Harbord & Marco Ottaviani, “Contracts and Competition in the Pay-TV Market,” London Bus. School Dep’t of Economics Working Paper No. DP 2001/5, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=289334. 
15 This phenomenon is known to economists as “double marginalization.”  Suppose the profit-maximizing price for ExtraInningsTM is $160/year.  (Any increase in price reduces demand, unless a product is essential to life.  Thus, raising the price from $150 to $160 will cause some marginal consumers to discontinue patronage, but if the number is small enough, the increase is profitable.  If 100 consumers refuse to go along with the increase, this would cost MLB/DirecTV $15,000.  But if a 10,000 consumers are willing to pay $160, this is an additional $100,000.  At some point, the number of consumers discontinuing purchases outweighs the additional income, just short of that point is the profit-maximizing price.)  If MLB sold rights on a per-subscriber basis, they would want to fix the price at $160 minus DirecTV’s costs.   If these costs were $5/subscriber, MLB would set the rights sale at $155.  However, this would leave DirecTV with no excess profits.  DirecTV would rather get some excess profits, even at the expense of losing some customers.  So DirecTV would be likely to charge $170 or more, costing MLB some customers and some profit.  These problems are avoided by a lump-sum sale.
16 Harbord & Ottaviani, supra, at 8.    To the extent that there are strategic gains from raising rivals’ cost, the incentive to re-sell is even stronger. 
17 Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 771 (1984).
18
 When the Supreme Court last revisited the issue in Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258 (1972), the Court explicitly rejected its original holding that baseball was not interstate commerce, instead re-affirming the exemption because of baseball’s “unique characteristics and needs” and Congress’ “positive inaction” in sustaining the judicial precedents.  It is clear that baseball has no unique characteristics and needs with regard to broadcasting, a fact Congress recognized by including baseball as a sport covered by the limited exemption for package sales to free-to-air networks contained in the Sports Broadcasting Act.  Congress’ positive inaction with regard to the baseball exemption, upon which Justice Blackmun relied in Flood, related almost entirely to labor restraints.  When Congress overturned that specific aspect of Flood in enacting the Curt Flood Act of 1995, it is clear that continuing legislative concern almost entirely related to protecting the unique characteristics and needs of minor league baseball, not broadcasting practices that MLB shares in common with the NBA and the NHL. 
 
            In addition, lower courts have suggested that the exemption applies only to the “business of baseball” and not to the “business of broadcasting.”  Henderson Broad. Corp. v. Houston Sports Ass'n, 541 F. Supp. 263 (S.D. Tex. 1982).  Especially in light of courts’ explicit recognition that MLB can lawfully require clubs to share revenues from rights sales, Chicago Professional Sports Ltd. Partnership, supra, 961 F.2d at 675, there is no reason why subjecting television agreements to standard antitrust analysis would compromise “the business of baseball.”
19 The current Supreme Court doctrine is expressed in Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984).  Firms engaged in a substantial amount of interstate commerce may not force consumers to purchase a product, service, or copyright license as a condition of purchasing a more desired license, where the seller has “market power,” the arrangement requires the purchase of two “separate products,” and the tying is not necessary to introduce a new product or to ensure the reliable use of either.  Applying this precedent, it is clear that DirecTV has market power in the sale of ExtraInningsTM, as there are no reasonable substitutes for out-of-market MLB games.  Forcing purchasers of ExtraInningsTM to purchase the Choice package constitutes a tied sale, because there is distinct and separate consumer demand for both products.  Finally, a there is no need to tie well-established programs in the Choice package with uniquely desirable MLB games in order to penetrate a market, and there are no reliability issues in subscribing to one or the other. 
20 See, e.g., Robert Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 365-381 (1978).
21 See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 487 (Scalia, J., dissenting); Hyde, 466 U.S. at 32 (O’Connor, J., concurring).
22
 William Howard Taft, The Anti-Trust Act and the Supreme Court (1914).
23 Valley Liquors, Inc. v. Renfield Importers, Ltd., 678 F.2d 742, 745 (7th Cir. 1982).
24 This legislation would also prevent cable companies from aggressively competing in a consumer-harming way by acquiring their own exclusive sports programming rights and refusing to re-sell to satellite outlets.
 
            Another example, of perhaps little interest to most Americans but of keen interest to millions, especially recent immigrants from south Asia or the United Kingdom, concerns the rights to satellite broadcasting of international cricket matches.  Thus, DishNetwork obtained exclusive rights for the International Cricket Council’s World Cup contests currently being played in the West Indies, while DirecTV obtained exclusive rights to a large number of international contests throughout the year.  Devoted cricket fans need to either subscribe to both or forego the ability to watch these matches in their homes.
25 The substance of the agreement, and whether the agreement or proposed legislation accurately reflects the public interest in an appropriate balance between protecting (i) players’ health, (ii) the integrity of the game from health-harming, performance-enhancing behavior, and (iii) privacy rights, is of course beyond the scope of this testimony as well as my scholarly expertise.
 
 
Banner

Poll

Should MLB Force Jeffery Loria to Sell the Marlins?