avodart coУЛt du mУЉdicament combien coУЛt de viagra par pillule au walmart le mУЉthotrexate 20 mg prix gУЉnУЉrique motrin quelle est la version gУЉnУЉrique de mircette voltaren gel de diclofenac sodique de gel topique prix la promУЉthazine w/ codУЉine prix de la rue bas prix en ligne viagra pilules va 50mg clomid de travail etodolac 400 mg reviews coУЛt de valtrex comprimУЉs tretinoin cream 0.025 acheter faux viagra pour la vente synthroid gУЉnУЉrique ok gУЉnУЉrique claritin prix le chlorhydrate de naltrexone en comprimУЉs usp 50 mg 150 mg cymbalta d'actualisation gУЉnУЉrique viagra inde prednisolone 5mg comprimУЉs et de l'alcool lisinopril prix walgreens methotrexate vente canada coУЛt de carafate sans assurance propranolol hcl de 40 mg coУЛt de valtrex avec blue cross blue shield la clindamycine topique nom gУЉnУЉrique effexor 75 mg vs celexa 20mg ce que je peux acheter sur le comptoir c'est comme le viagra voltaren acheter royaume-uni puis-je donner mon chien claritin gУЉnУЉrique puis-je acheter propranolol sur le comptoir en espagne furosemide actavis 40 mg, tabletten zoloft ordonnance au canada medicamento viagra 50 mg la prise de 200 mg de clomid metformin gУЉnУЉrique photos propecia 1 mg ou 5mg ranitidine 150 mg indikasi augmentin 1000 duo prix en inde allegra d coupons de rУЉduction le finastУЉride gУЉnУЉrique versus propecia nombre generico de cymbalta neurontin 100 mg precio quand crestor ont un gУЉnУЉrique acheter accutane uk acheter У bas prix nolvadex royaume-uni lopid 900 mg pfizer 5 mg celexa anxiУЉtУЉ ordonnance motrin photos indication de ciprofloxacin 500mg abilify 5 mg la dУЉpressionnorvasc dose de 15 mg tofranil acheter est-il un gУЉnУЉrique tretinoin gel utilise pour tetracycline 500mg cymbalta 60 mg nota 4 qu'est-ce que cipro xl 1000 mg utilisУЉ pour remedio motilium 10mg quel est le coУЛt de plavix au walmart nom gУЉnУЉrique pour zanaflex risperdal pour le trouble oppositionnel avec provocation comment utiliser vermox 100mg prednisolone 5 mg ml risperdal trouble borderline buspar pour le trouble panique lisinopril 40 mg prix de walmart walgreens pharmacie prednisone est-il un gУЉnУЉrique pour diovan hct avec seroquel xr pharmacie en ligne combien sont cialis pilules naltrexone 50 mg demi-vie glucophage 500 mg par jour y aura-il un gУЉnУЉrique pour nexium voltaren 100mg utilise zyban bon de rУЉduction achat doxycycline en ligne cialis daily 2,5 mg coУЛt est provera 10mg un contraceptif diovan gУЉnУЉrique disponible au canada est-il un gУЉnУЉrique similaires pour cymbalta zyprexa gУЉnУЉrique examens zithromax 600 mg comprimУЉs accutane effets secondaires 40 mg synthroid 0,1 mg inderal la 80 mg coУЛt xenical pic de ventes cialis pour la vente en philippines zyprexa 2.5 mg et prise de poids lipitor gУЉnУЉrique autorisУЉ watson gУЉnУЉrique motrin 800 mg combien coУЛte une prescription de viagra des coУЛts liquide benadryl ou de pilules lexapro 5 mg efficacitУЉ combien 10mg amitriptyline pouvez-vous prendre est-il un lieu sУЛr pour acheter du viagra en ligne effets secondaires de lipitor gУЉnУЉrique paxil livraison le lendemain ne strattera besoin d'une ordonnance rite aid allegra coУЛt aciclovir 800 mg tabletas genfar cardizem cd 360 mg prix cat costa valtrex zocor 40 mg effets secondaires prednisone 50 mg deux fois par jour seroquel pour vente en ligne forme gУЉnУЉrique nexium d'aide aux patients wellbutrin canada coreg 5 mg acheter minocycline canada augmentin-offre sУМspansiyon 200/ 28 mg 100 ml ne lipitor venir sous forme gУЉnУЉrique viagra-canada.com effexor trouble dУЉpressif majeur topamax le trouble bipolaire oУЙ acheter maxalt fondre У bas prix les gУЉnУЉriques pharmacie cytotec norvasc 5 mg d'amlodipine gУЉnУЉrique viagra soft tabs cardizem 20 mg iv aciclovir 400 mg vo prometrium prescription de chlorhydrate de bupropion 300 mg prednisone nom de marque canada zetia prescription coupons tamoxifen troubles de la peau metoprolol tablette mga la clindamycine-mip 600 mg comprimУЉs baclofen 10 mg, comparativement У soma commander viagra pilules prednisone 10 mg ressembler clomid pct acheter royaume-uni comprimУЉ de cialis 20 mg voltaren 50 mg de l'allaitement maternel furosemide pour vente royaume-uni effets secondaires de 15 mg de prednisone u peut obtenir haut sur etodolac 400 mg tretinoin pharmacie mexique paroxetine hcl 10mg reviews 200 mg de doxycycline pour l'acnУЉ acheter cytotec en ligne pas cher nexium esomeprazol 10 mg prospect le sevrage arrУЊt de la fluoxУЉtine 20 mg acheter du viagra au kenya coУЛt de voltaren 1 gel risperdal gУЉnУЉrique autorisУЉ oУЙ puis-je acheter phenergan 25mg fungsi dramamine 50 mg metoprolol succ er prix combien de temps zanaflex 4 mg sУЉjour dans votre systУЈme qu'est-ce que seroquel xr 50 mg cymbalta ordonnance canada actos gУЉnУЉrique date de sortie cymbalta bouchon 60mg pouvez-vous acheter prevacid sur le comptoir au canada doxycycline 100mg comprimУЉ quel est le coУЛt de gУЉnУЉrique lamictal nexium prix en dollars acheter du viagra У new york gУЉnУЉrique proscar (finasteride 5mg) comment commander topamax en ligne acheter differin 0.3 gel en ligne coУЛt de neurontin 100mg diltiazem 240 mg cd cap kegunaan crestor rosuvastatine 20 mg meilleur prix pour lipitor 10mg tenormin 50 mg atenolol exelon patch pour la vente moins cher viagra 100mg pouvez-vous acheter propecia sur le comptoir au canada bupropion er 200 mg effets secondaires pouvez-vous acheter isotretinoin en ligne acheter clomid et arimidex taux de rУЉussite sur clomid 50mg neurontin meilleur prix vytorin en generico est nexium otc la mУЊme que sur ordonnance diflucan 150 mg mexique wellbutrin coupons de rУЉductions canadien de la colchicine diovan prix de walmart peut prendre de 2 У 200 mg de celebrex flonase vs nasacort coУЛt requip pharmacie en ligne retane l'isotrУЉtinoУЏne 20 mg oУЙ puis-je acheter cialis en vancouver zovirax pommade ordonnance cialis generico 20mg nom gУЉnУЉrique adalat xl l'expУЉdition de nuit pour cialis puis-je acheter zovirax en ligne lamictal dc 25 mg nedir prevacid pilules estomac bula wellbutrin xl 150mg valtrex gУЉnУЉrique posologie le citrate de clomifУЈne clomid acheter est allegra sur le comptoir mУЊme que sur ordonnance gУЉnУЉrique cardizem cd 120 mg ordonnance viagra nz gУЉnУЉrique de lexapro prix cvs prix pour valtrex viagra pour la vente en jhb estrace cream de canadian pharmacy combien abilify 5mg coУЛt prednisone 20 mg maux de dos cytotec 200 mg indication plavix 75 mg prix canada cytotec avortement pilules effets secondaires acheter allopurinol en ligne sevrage paroxetine 20mg quel est le gУЉnУЉrique du cymbalta metoprolol tarte film-ctd 100 mg olanzapine en ligne acheter 90 mg de cymbalta quotidien pouvez-vous acheter viagra У dubaУЏ zyrtec vs gУЉnУЉriques propranolol 60 mg pour l'anxiУЉtУЉ 100 У 150 mg de zoloft tomei viagra generico cephalexin 500 mg 4 fois par jour enceinte ranitidine 150 mg avantages meilleur endroit pour acheter dapoxetine zyvox gУЉnУЉrique date glycomet gp 0,5 mg seroquel coУЛts ne allegra ont un gУЉnУЉrique effets secondaires du buspar 5mg diovan gУЉnУЉrique va prix de cialis 5mg au walmart ne lexapro aider avec des troubles de l'alimentation le shampooing nizoral oУЙ acheter nyc imitrex au-dessus du compteur canada topamax 50 mg coУЛt royaume-uni prix de viagra achat de viagra en playa del carmen au mexique version gУЉnУЉrique du plavix lexapro gУЉnУЉrique coУЛt cible cialis pour la vente en jamaУЏque voltaren suppositoire У 100 mg phenergan con la codУЉine nombre generico achat de viagra avec paypal est viagra disponible sous forme gУЉnУЉrique encore cialis 50 mg pret gУЉnУЉriques pour diflucan 150 mg acheter viagra adelaide pouvez-vous acheter lexapro sur le comptoir a 6 benadryl pilules nexium bouchons 20mg strattera 10 mg tablette ne walmart vente clomid meilleur prix pour aciphex hyzaar de 100 mg celebrex prix walgreens voltaren 75 mg comprimУЉ fiyatФБ trazodone pilules contre la douleur pouvez-vous acheter viagra en ligne les rУЉponses de yahoo fosamax canadian pharmacy minocycline hcl 100mg utilise combien coУЛte lamisil coУЛt au canada viagra 25mg en ligne prix de la doxycycline monohydrate quel est le gУЉnУЉrique diltiazem prix du crestor au walmart pharmacie viagra marque, acheter cymbalta 20 mg prix finasteride 5 mg actavis nexium 40 mg injectabil perspective qu'est-ce que la force de prescription claritin pouvez-vous obtenir haut de zoloft 50 mg clomid pilules pour la vente est le nom gУЉnУЉrique lisinopril coУЛt de metoprolol xl est l-thyroxine gУЉnУЉrique pour synthroid depo-provera 50mg ml tadacip pille 20mg cialis generika combien est viagra coУЛt en irlande motrin 600 mg de l'allaitement maternel quel est le coУЛt de exelon patch prix de la metformine 850 mg effexor xr gУЉnУЉrique coУЛt pouvez-vous acheter arimidex sur le comptoir vertige meclizine 25 mg prednisone pharmacie prix provera 10mg et les crampes est de 25 mg de viagra assez ranitidine sirop de coУЛt canadian generic viagra en pharmacie levitra 20 mg 4 film tablette oУЙ puis-je acheter cytotec pilules viagra super force canada augmentin 500 mg tabletki j code pour zyvox 600 mg gУЉnУЉriques pour ventolin inhalateur furosemide gУЉnУЉrique formulaire celebrex prix par pilule acheter levitra avec paypal tretinoin 0.1 canada 875 mg augmentin pour infection urinaire nexium comprimУЉs 40mg posologie puis-je prendre deux pilules benadryl gУЉnУЉrique synthroid la perte de cheveux advair coУЛt de la pompe diflucan 150 mg acheter en ligne lamictal 1200 mg est-il un gУЉnУЉrique version de nexium ce qui est gУЉnУЉrique prilosec cephalexin 500mg en inde est-il la force de prescription allegra skelaxin 800 mg maux de dos coУЛt de la synthroid vs gУЉnУЉriques hydrochlorothiazide 50 mg image cialis 20mg comprimУЉs prix coУЛt de nexium pilules lipitor marque gУЉnУЉrique doxycycline prix des mУЉdicaments gУЉnУЉriques acheter metformin 500 bupropion sr 100mg augmentin comprimУЉ oral 875-125 mg canadian pharmacy viagra cipa le mexique pharmacie accutane des rУЉductions pour augmentin seroquel gУЉnУЉrique les noms de combien de pilules de lexapro t-il jusqu'У l'overdose prednisone 20 mg effet forme gУЉnУЉrique de avalide diovan au costco propranolol eg 40 mg tegretol canada singulair pic de ventes est aciphex gУЉnУЉrique aller seroquel trouble dissociatif adalat eins 30mg metformin hcl er comprimУЉ de 500 mg de perte de poids celexa et le trouble bipolaire viagra privУЉ, le coУЛt des ordonnances viagra 25 mg 4 tablette fiyatФБ acheter synthroid pas cher ce qui est bactrim ds pilules acheter ventolin pilules zovirax pomada 50mg aciclovir pomada mg acheter nizoral ketoconazole shampoing claritin 20 mg dose comment est-il sУЛr de commander viagra en ligne oУЙ puis-je acheter viagra en ligne en usa ranitidine zantac gУЉnУЉrique combien coreg coУЛt viagra vente en philippines dose de charge de plavix 600 mg seroquel 20 mg effets secondaires doxycycline 100mg pbs acheter antabuse en ligne australie acheter eldepryl site sУЉcuritaire d'acheter du viagra les coУЛts de viagra vs cialis 10mg de prednisone coУЛt aciclovir 400 mg jarabe oУЙ puis-je obtenir viagra pour acheter au ghana wellbutrin 100 mg par jour mУЉdicaments gУЉnУЉriques pour sinemet provera 1 mg combien de temps de 30 mg de prednisone dernier effets secondaires de la clindamycine 300 mg capsules oУЙ puis-je acheter diovan 160 mg avalide gУЉnУЉrique effets secondaires fiable pour acheter clomid composicion cialis 20 mg celexa pour traiter le trouble bipolaire quels pays pouvez-vous acheter viagra sur le comptoir diltiazem hcl er 240 mg le shampooing nizoral livraison internationale acheter propecia canada pharmacie 250 mg de zoloft j'ai besoin d'acheter prednisone cialis versus viagra prix combien de follicules sur clomid 25mg finasteride da 1 mg propranolol 10 mg d'alcool amitriptyline hydrochloride 10mg et de l'alcool flomax 0.4 mg m. kapsУМl 30 cap pilules de testostУЉrone vs viagra photos prilosec pilules zestril 10 mg image etodolac 300 mg coУЛt seroquel xr 50 mg pour le sommeil propranolol gУЉnУЉrique et un nom commercial oУЙ acheter du viagra У pУЉkin l'arrУЊt seroquel 25mg quand avez-crestor devenir gУЉnУЉrique doxepin neuraxpharm 10 mg seroquel quetiapine 25 mg prednisone 50 mg en cas d'УЉruption cutanУЉe alternative moins coУЛteuse pour strattera zoloft 100 mg ms la prescription du viagra cipla cialis gУЉnУЉrique examens aciclovir comprimУЉs de 600 mg dilantin prix en inde viagra canada paypal l'УЉrythromycine see 400 mg tab ne nexium ont un gУЉnУЉrique qu'est-ce que tamoxifen 10 mg benicar pilules de pression artУЉrielle ordre tetracycline en ligne royaume-uni oУЙ puis-je acheter viagra en adelaide prednisolone 5mg co jest 60 mg tamoxifen phenergan somnifУЈres puis-je acheter viagra au cambodge quel est le prix du cytotec dans les philippines prevacid 15 mg sur le comptoir effets secondaires ciprofloxacin 750 mg l'obtention d'une ordonnance zoloft azulfidine 500mg ra lisinopril royaume-uni coУЛt prednisone en ligne durant la nuit le coУЛt de cymbalta canada lУЉgitime endroit pour acheter cialis trazodone 100 mg vous haute harga glucophage 850 mg acheter du viagra en ligne commande de la boutique amox - augmentin 875 mg clopidogrel actavis 75 mg effets secondaires pilules de contrУДle des naissances et У la ciprofloxacine est tamsulosine gУЉnУЉrique pour flomax norvasc prix aux etats-unis 1800 mg de wellbutrin hydrochlorothiazide lisinopril 12,5 mg / 20 mg gУЉnУЉrique ventolin inhalateur en ligne oУЙ obtenir viagra ordonnance qui rend gУЉnУЉrique toprol xl acheter accutane d'actualitУЉ achat de viagra au royaume-uni est gУЉnУЉrique synthroid bon valsartan gУЉnУЉrique pour diovan existe-t-cialis generico en mexico celexa programme de rabais co-paroxetine 30 mg aldara coУЛt walmart ordonnance pour inderal indications pour la prise de prednisone 10mg dose pack nizoral 200 mg posologie flomax tamsulosine 0,4 mg augmentin 625mg prix en inde zocor prix philippines chloramphenicol 250 mg dosage pouvez-vous acheter diflucan sur le comptoir dans etats-unis effets secondaires de 20 mg de prednisone, neurontin 100 mg tablette est-il un mУЉdicament gУЉnУЉrique de plavix achetez wellbutrin xl en ligne canadien de la pharmacie tamoxifen amitriptyline 50 mg pour l'anxiУЉtУЉ tabletas bactrim dose de 160 mg meclizine hcl 25 mg tablette diltiazem hcl 30 mg tablette 250 mg de metformine sopk long terme des effets secondaires de prevacid 30 mg topamax 50 mg prospect gУЉnУЉrique seroquel 400 mg augmentin 875 mg pour infection de la vessie altace hct 10/12.5 mg ordonnance non paroxetine 100 mg indocin nom gУЉnУЉrique lisinopril oz pilules cialis est de 37,5 mg d'effexor assez provera 5 mg costo acheter seroquel en ligne pas cher cialis prix costco indication augmentin 500 mg diflucan posologie de 200 mg benadryl 50 mg im cataflam 50 mg de diclofУЉnac potassique gУЉnУЉrique singulair ont gluten acheter finasteride 5mg xenical gУЉnУЉrique (orlistat) costo cialis chili 20 mg cialis daily viagra royaume-uni coУЛt mУЉdicament gУЉnУЉrique УЉquivalent de crestor gУЉnУЉrique zofran sans danger durant la grossesse l'ampicilline 50 mg/ml meilleur pharmacie pour acheter gУЉnУЉrique viagra prix pour keflex levitra prix chez walmart est de 500 mg de metformine assez pour le sopk synthroid 112 mg bula skelaxin 800 mg relaxant musculaire combien coУЛt de la colchicine acheter aldara royaume-uni l'isotrУЉtinoУЏne canada zithromax 500 mg spc comment puis-je obtenir une ordonnance accutane effets secondaires du micardis plus 40 mg une ordonnance est nУЉcessaire pour valtrex comprimУЉs de prednisone 20 mg pour les chiens la nystatine et d'acУЉtonide de triamcinolone cream sans prescription acheter du viagra pas cher canada acheter metoprolol tartrate rУЉussite avec clomid 100mg 200 mg zoloft grossesse
Home Media News Opening Statement: Stephen F. Ross on DirecTV Deal

Like Shoot to Thrill - An AC/DC Tribute on Facebook!

An authentic tribute of AC/DC that covers the best of the Bon Scott era and the best of Brian Johnson's material

Who's Online?

We have 1197 guests online

Atom RSS

Opening Statement: Stephen F. Ross on DirecTV Deal PDF Print E-mail
User Rating: / 10
PoorBest 
Written by Stephen F. Ross   
Tuesday, 27 March 2007 04:32
RESTORING THE MARKET FOR OUT-OF-MARKET BASEBALL
Testimony of Professor Stephen F. Ross
Director, Penn State Institute for Sports Law, Policy and Research
The Pennsylvania State University
Before the
Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation
March 27, 2007
 
Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee:
 
          It is an honor and privilege to be invited to join a panel of industry leaders to offer an independent view, based on over two decades of scholarship and teaching concerning sports and competition policy, in discussing the impediments to the free flow of interstate commerce as millions of Americans seek ways to take advantage of technological advances to watch non-local Major League Baseball games in their homes.
 
General Thoughts on Exclusive Dealing
 
          The issue before the Committee today is whether the exclusive dealing arrangement between Major League Baseball (MLB) and DirecTV, whereby DirecTV becomes the only source for out-of-market games not shown on national networks, is in the public interest.  As the Supreme Court has recognized,1 exclusive dealing arrangements are both legitimate and indeed can have pro-competitive effects.  In traditional markets where consumers have free access to retail markets, the Court has declared that, as a matter of antitrust law (in my view, this reasoning also applies to sound regulatory policy), these arrangements should only be questioned when there is a serious risk that they will foreclose access to supply or outlet by other firms.2  Thus, an agreement by Sears to exclusively sell Levi’s blue jeans is unlikely to harm consumers; there are ample other retail outlets for Levi’s rivals, and ample other jean manufacturers for Sears’ competitors.  If there are efficiencies in exclusivity, the likely market response is for Lee to reach an exclusive deal with Macy’s, etc.   Consumers unhappy with Sears’ selection are only harmed to the extent they have to walk across the shopping mall.
 
Harm to baseball fans
 
          In contrast, baseball fans face significant harm because of various pre-existing agreements as well as the recently announced exclusive MLB/DirecTV deal.   Those who have other reasons to prefer DishNetwork or cable must either forego quality telecasts of out-of-market baseball games,3 or suffer exploitation by subscribing to multiple multi-channel video distribution platforms that require the purchase of duplicate programming and unnecessary equipment.  The exclusive deal reinforces the harm that already befalls the millions of Americans who do not live within the local media market of their favorite team, because of a horizontal market division agreement entered into by MLB owners that, in the context of football, has been illegal for over 50 years.4  There is no public interest justification in forcing consumers to purchase a distribution platform that is inferior for their needs, or duplicate platforms, just to watch their favorite teams.  These consumers include:
 
  • Residents in areas with heavy thunderstorm activity (such as Florida) who prefer cable because of concerns about weather-related interference with important sports broadcasts
  • Residents of local markets (like metropolitan Philadelphia and southern New Jersey) who are fans of local basketball and hockey teams but out-of-market baseball teams, and would under planned agreements be required to subscribe to cable for some teams and satellite for others
  • Virtually all residents of states without a local team (like Alaska, Hawaii, or Nevada) or states with many retirees from other states (like Florida, California, or Arizona): there is no reason that the only way they can watch games of their favorite teams is to acquire a single product, MLB ExtraInningsTM,  from a single retailer, DirecTV
  • Consumers in multi-residence dwellings who are not allowed to select their preferred retailer, and where the landlord, homeowners’ association, or other decision-maker is insufficiently interested in baseball to switch to DirecTV
 
(Select Read More to see the rest of Ross' opening statement)
 
Restraints on Interstate Commerce: Horizontal Market Division
 
          To be clear, the agreement that sparked this hearing did not arise from the free market.  First, there is the horizontal market division by MLB owners.  Under the common law, the home team owns a property right in the radio and television rights to baseball games.5  However, the MLB owners have agreed to significant limitations on these common law rights.  Each club will only broadcast games in its assigned geographic territory, licensing the visiting club for the purpose of broadcasting games in its own home territory, and assigning to MLB the exclusive right to sell games not only to free-to-air networks (a right protected by the Sports Broadcasting Act) but most significantly the exclusive right to sell non-network games to satellite or cable only through MLB ExtraInningsTM (which is not exempt from antitrust scrutiny). 
 
          Were it not for this web of agreements, the MLB/DirecTV deal would raise few problems for consumers.  Those interested in the convenience of a single package of all out-of-market games could purchase ExtraInningsTM from DirecTV.  A Los Angeles Dodgers fan outside southern California, or someone who simply enjoyed the final years of play-by-play from hall-of-famer Vin Scully, would likely find it possible to purchase Dodger telecasts, acquired from the Dodgers by DirecTV, DishNetwork, or the local cable company.  Other intermediaries might offer a syndicate of games in competition with ExtraInningsTM.
 
          Antitrust precedents suggest that the MLB agreements are anti-competitive and ought to be illegal.  In United States v. National Football League,6 a very sophisticated district court decision that presaged by 30 years the antitrust analysis of broadcast restraints later adopted by the Supreme Court,7 the court noted that sports leagues had a unique interest in promoting competitive balance among member teams so that, to the extent that a rival team’s out-of-market telecast would significantly harm live attendance, the league could agree to prevent this.  However, the court rejected the NFL’s effort to bar out-of-market telecasts that simply competed with the home team’s telecast of road games: the only effect there was to limit output and raise rights fees for the home team, a result that was not legitimate or pro-competitive.  As later courts have recognized,8 leagues can adequately protect competitive balance with regard to television rights sales by revenue sharing, rather than output limits. 
 
          The courts have also recognized, in antitrust litigation, that broad licenses awarded by competing copyright holders through intermediaries can be pro-competitive, when these are non-exclusive licenses.  Thus, the Supreme Court rejected a lower court holding that Broadcast Music and ASCAP violated the Sherman Act by offering a blanket license for the vast majority of copyrighted songs.9 On remand, the court of appeals upheld the legality of the arrangement, but only after finding that potential licensees had real alternative ways of acquiring rights.10  This was because the Justice Department had challenged, many years ago, the agreement among almost all the nation’s songwriters to grant exclusive licenses to BMI or ASCAP – grants akin to the out-of-market assignments that individual team owners have made to DirecTV -- and the parties by consent decree had agreed to limit the license to a non-exclusive grant.11
 
          It is bad enough that these agreements meet the “hallmark” definition of unreasonable restraints of trade, by increasing price, reducing output, and rendering output unresponsive to consumer demand.12  In fact, these agreements are even more inefficient and anti-competitive than would be the case if all rights to all games were assigned to a single entity.  Because the additional costs of showing games to out-of-market fans is virtually zero, such an entity would likely sell, in addition to local rights and ExtraInningsTM, other packages to other consumers.  For example, there are surely many fans who would pay, on a per game or per team basis, for out-of-market games.  These are not authorized now, not because the sale would not be profitable, but because the MLB owners can not agree on how to divide the profits.13
 
Insufficient competition in multi-channel video distribution
 
          An analysis of the economics of rights sales for out-of-market games demonstrates that the current scheme would be implausible except for two additional deviations from the free market: (1) insufficient competition between DirecTV, DishNetwork, and cable permits excess profits from consumers of “basic premium” programming; (2) by tying the sale of ExtraInningsTM to its “Choice” package, DirecTV is able to increase its excess profits and the agreement in question reflects a sharing of those increased excess profits between DirecTV and Major League Baseball.
 
          Although there are important differences in the economics of English football and North American sports, on both sides of the Atlantic we see leagues that offer entertainment products with no reasonable substitutes selling broadcast rights to a major programmer in return for a large, fixed sum of money.  Policy questions about exclusive agreements for prime sports programming have also arisen in the United Kingdom, and have been insightfully analyzed in a working paper widely distributed among sports economists.14  Economists David Harbord and Marco Ottaviani detail the profit-maximizing strategy for the various market participants.  First, they note that leagues are likely to sell rights for a fixed rather than per-subscriber fee.  A fixed fee avoids the problem of the rights-purchaser tacking on its own excess profits charge to that imposed by the league.15  Because MLB doesn’t know precisely how many fans will subscribe to ExtraInningsTM, or how effectively DirecTV will market the product, it has an even greater incentive to sell for fixed fees, as the rights-purchaser is better able to accept the risk of marketing the product effectively during the course of the contract.  If the rights purchaser is effective in maximizing revenues from resale and advertising, results of which are usually reported in the trade press, the league can profit from the rights purchaser’s success to secure even higher rights fees for the next contract.  (For example, the NFL’s first network contract with CBS gave each owner $300,000/yr.  Three years later, the second contract gave each owner $1 million/yr.)
 
          Next, Harbord & Ottaviani explain why a rights-purchaser, having paid a lump-sum to obtain rights for which there was no substitute, would want to re-sell rights on a per-subscriber basis to its cable and satellite rivals.  Ordinarily, they observe, by re-selling to rivals, the rights purchaser increases the marginal operating costs for its rivals at the same time it fetches additional revenue.  This “makes reselling more profitable for the firm which acquires the rights, and hence more likely to occur.”16  Re-selling on a per-subscriber basis results in higher rights fees (because the league can capture a portion of the additional profit to be obtained from reselling on a per-subscriber basis) and maximizes output (more people subscribe).
 
          Applied to American baseball, Harbord & Ottaviani’s analysis suggests that DirecTV would find it profitable to resell ExtraInnings to cable networks and Dish Network, and that MLB would share in this profit through a higher lump-sum fee for the exclusive rights to out-of-market baseball games.  So why have DirecTV and MLB done the opposite?  We can infer from the parties’ preference for an exclusive deal that DirecTV is willing to forego this opportunity, and indeed pay MLB more than the total amount that MLB might reasonably expect to receive from sales of ExtraInnings through various retail outlets.  This is because DirecTV would prefer to force some out-of-market baseball fans to switch their patronage to DirecTV, rather than obtain all the revenue from out-of-market fans, regardless of which “retailer” these fans patronize.  DirecTV’s ability to obtain more revenue from those fans that remain with or switch to DirecTV than it could by charging the full monopoly price for ExtraInningsTM to all out-of-market fans is most likely due to their ability to obtain even greater super-competitive profits from those that switch.
 
     Suppose one million fans would be willing to subscribe to ExtraInningsTM at $160 per season, but that 200,000 of these will not patronize DirecTV (perhaps they fear thunderstorms, prefer programming available only on cable, can’t afford two systems in areas where local cable is unavailable, don’t have a clear south-facing view on their property, must use the system subscribed by the landlord, etc.).  That’s $32 million in lost revenue.  The exclusive deal means that DirecTV plans on making this up by obtaining new customers from cable or DishNetwork.  If 300,000 ExtraInnings customers switch to DirecTV’s Choice package (at $480/yr) + ExtraInningsTM, that’s an additional $144 million in revenue (from Choice, not MLB games, which these fans were already purchasing via cable or DishNetwork).  If DirecTV’s operational and programming costs in servicing the new customers was not well below $144 million, this scheme wouldn’t be profitable.  Only the excess profits on the Choice package – which baseball fans are required to purchase as a condition of subscribing to ExtraInningsTM, – is what allows DirecTV to profitably enter into an exclusive deal.
 
    One other explanation is theoretically possible – that there are huge cost-saving efficiencies from an exclusive dealing arrangement.  However, no one has, to date, seriously made this claim on behalf of MLB or DirecTV.
 
Summary of economic analysis

    The foregoing analysis suggests that the MLB/DirecTV exclusive deal reflects the ability of these sellers to exploit baseball fans because of the lack of any substitute products, and thus impose a monopoly price and significantly reduce output.  Out-of-market games will henceforth only be available on DirecTV, presumably at the monopoly price.  The absence of alternative means of obtaining out-of-market games means millions of consumers will pay more.  But it also means that output is substantially reduced, because of foregone purchases (all of which would be considerably above the marginal cost of production) from (i) expatriate fans of one particular team willing to pay a lower price to watch their favorite team but unwilling to pay for the ExtraInnings package; (ii) avid fans who have other preferential reasons to prefer to continue to subscribe to cable or Dish Network; (iii) marginal customers of satellite programming, who otherwise prefer DirecTV’s programming but decline to pay the “basic premium” price charged by DirecTV because it reflects in part the need to share profits with MLB.  This is bad public policy.
 
Ways that legislation can protect consumers
 
    There are a number of ways that existing or potential legislation could protect baseball fans against exploitation by inefficient and anti-competitive broadcast agreements:
 
  • Existing antitrust laws could be used to invalidate these unreasonable restraints of trade.
  • Specific antitrust legislation could be enacted to facilitate this result.
  • Regulatory legislation could minimize the excess profits that satellite and cable providers enjoy from their “basic premium” packages, or could directly prohibit the bundling essential to the exclusivity scheme by requiring “a la carte” pricing.
  • Strategic legislation could also be introduced by leading members of this committee as a means of facilitating voluntary pro-consumer compliance by industry.

Existing antitrust enforcement
 
    As detailed below, even vigorous enforcement of the antitrust laws by the Justice Department would face significant obstacles to quick resolution in time to protect sports fans.  Unfortunately, the record of the current Antitrust Division leadership does not lead to a confident prediction of such enforcement.  The obstacles to private litigation to effectively protect consumers are even greater.  For these reasons, reliance on existing law is unlikely to constitute an adequate public policy response by this Congress. 
 
    A government enforcement action should be able to rely on the precedents discussed above to establish that the horizontal restraint among MLB clubs is an unreasonable restraint of trade.  The exclusive broadcast territories are neither necessary to promote competitive balance among member teams nor to prevent any efficiency-deterring free riding. The only way in which a club’s sale of their games into another geographic market could harm competitive balance would be if the additional revenue generated from these out-of-market rights fees would enable the teams to acquire enough talent to enable them to dominate the league. This scenario is implausible for a number of reasons. There is no evidence that these fees would be significant enough to affect competitive balance. More important, there is no reason why the leagues could not share these revenues, as Major League Baseball has with teams whose games are carried nationwide via locally-based superstations.
 
    Nor can the leagues, in this context, sensibly claim that the restraint is an intra-firm restraint among the “single entity” of the league, rather than the horizontal agreement among independent clubs.  Because of the economics of rights sales, a single firm would sell all rights in all games that are going to be televised to the highest bidder, who could then re-sell the games to consumers in a price discriminating manner designed to yield the greatest revenue (noting again that the marginal costs of selling a game once it is being televised is virtually zero).  The ExtraInnings package is the only way that out-of-market fans can get games, not because this is DirecTV’s preference, but because it is the choice of the majority of MLB clubs.  DirecTV would clearly be better off if it could price discriminate by selling the ExtraInnings package to those with a demand for over 1,000 baseball games, and selling a smaller package of games (or even individual games on a pay-per-view basis) to its subscribers unwilling to pay for ExtraInnings.  Rather, individual games are unavailable to out-of-market fans, despite the potential for profitable sales, because transactions costs prevent owners from agreeing on how to divide the spoils.  As a result, the interest of the league-as-a-whole in maximizing revenues from television sales is subordinated to the interests of individual teams in protecting their own local broadcast rights and preventing rivals from attaining a competitive advantage from more successful out-of-market rights sales.  This is not the “unity of interest” that the Supreme Court has required to exclude agreements among formally separate entities from review under section 1 of the Sherman Act.17
 
    Existing precedents with regard to tying arrangements might also support a claim that DirecTV’s practice of bundling ExtraInningsTM with its $40/mo. Choice package is also unreasonable.  However, there are several serious obstacles to successful government prosecution of such a lawsuit.  First, MLB could claim that the judicially-created baseball exemption applies to broadcast restraints.  Although good arguments can be made that the exemption does not apply,18 the result is ultimately an uncertain question likely to require ultimate resolution, after years of litigation, by the Supreme Court.  Second, although DirecTV’s bundling practices would appear to be unreasonable under existing precedents,19these precedents have come under criticism by commentators20 and justices.21  Moreover, current regulation of cable and satellite practices by the FCC might be held to preclude antitrust scrutiny of this behavior. 
 
    Private enforcement is even more problematic.  The obstacles stated above pose major litigation risks that would deter private antitrust attorneys from commencing expensive litigation.  Because the proposed exclusive deal is prospective, treble damage relief (and accompanying attorneys fees funded by the damage award) would not be available for that aspect of the challenge.  My own experience as a public interest advocate has been that private firms are unlikely to view the grant of statutory attorneys fees provided for in the Clayton Act as a sufficient economic incentive to undertake the costs of uncertain litigation.  In addition, private litigation on behalf of consumers who currently patronize DirecTV would have to confront complex issues that would arise in light of the contract-by-adhesion DirecTV requires all customers that provides for disputes to be arbitrated.
 

New antitrust legislation
 
    This Committee could defer to your Judiciary Committee colleagues, who could consider specific legislation that amended the Sports Broadcasting Act to prohibit the sort of bundling or exclusive dealing practices identified in this testimony.  There is a long history of specific legislation enacted by Congress to outlaw specific anti-competitive practices: indeed, the Clayton Act was passed to specifically outlaw tying arrangements arguably illegal under the Sherman Act, over the objections of former President William Howard Taft, who left the White House to accepted a chaired professorship at Yale Law School and wrote a book arguing for the adequacy of the Sherman Act on this and other points.22
 
Regulatory legislation
 
    As Judge Richard Posner famously observed, a “firm that has no market power is unlikely to adopt policies that disserve its consumers; it cannot afford to. And if it blunders and does adopt such a policy, market retribution will be swift.”23  The corollary, of course, is that firms with market power can afford to disserve consumers and market retribution will not be swift. 
 
    Either expressly, or by delegation to the FCC, this Committee could craft legislation that recognizes that market retribution is not swift in either the market for out-of-market baseball games or the market for delivery of multi-channel video distribution.  A variety of regulatory approaches might be considered.  I would be pleased to continue to work with you and your staff if any of these are of particular interest:
 
  • Listed Events Legislation: A variety of other countries have enacted legislation that specifically requires a variety of important sporting events to remain on free-to-air television, for the benefit of millions of consumers.
  • “A La Carte” Pricing: Satellite and cable companies could be prohibited from requiring lengthy subscriptions to their “basic premium” packages as a condition of subscription to high-demand sport programming.  The analysis above suggests that DirecTV would quickly lose its incentive to pay MLB for exclusive rights if cable subscribers could, in a secondary market, acquire DirecTV equipment and then simply subscribe to ExtraInningsTM without having to pay $40/mo. for Choice.
  • Specifically Ban Sports Exclusivity: Unlike general delegations contained in the Sherman Act or the Federal Communications Act, Congress is free to write specific legislation to deal with specific industry problems.  Based on the economic analysis summarized above, the Committee could conclude that copyright holders and their licensees can fully exploit their intellectual property rights by sale and re-sale and there is no legitimate justification (sharing in excess profits from limited retail competition is not legitimate) for exclusive agreements in this area.24
 
Strategic behavior – by Major League Baseball and by the Senate Commerce Committee
 
    Both business and political actors often behave strategically – they act in a way that may or may not further immediate short-run goals in order to achieve long-run objectives.  Although MLB owners are rightly accused of being short-sighted and greedy in some instances, there are many other occasions where MLB owners have decided that the long-term health of the National Pastime is more important.  It is possible that this is one of those occasions: that MLB owners see a strong future in the development of The Baseball Channel, and the exclusive agreement with DirecTV is simply a negotiating strategy to persuade DishNetwork and cable companies to re-sell The Baseball Channel on favorable terms.
 
    If market retribution were swift among cable and satellite programmers, this would not be a problem.  If MLB’s demands were not unreasonable, then so many consumers would shift to DirecTV that rival MVPDs would have to go along.  If MLB’s demands were unreasonable, then DirecTV would lose so much money that it would eventually back out.  However, anyone inside the Beltway is familiar with the lack of swift retribution reflected in the lengthy negotiations that were required before millions of Capital-area baseball fans could obtain Washington Nationals local broadcasts on their stations.  The FCC has already recognized that market retribution is not swift in a number of non-sports contexts involving cable mergers, requiring programmers and distributors to either reach agreement on terms or submit their unresolved disputes to binding commercial arbitration.   
 
    There are a variety of situations where public policy may require government intervention, but where the best solution would be a voluntary agreement among private parties rather than direct legislation.  An excellent example of that technique was recently employed by this Committee, when under Senator McCain’s chairmanship there were explicit overtures to MLB owners and players to agree on new procedures for steroid testing or face federal legislative intervention.  The result was a voluntary deal that is probably superior to anything Congress could have done.25
 
    Likewise, if it appears that the best resolution of this controversy is voluntary agreement among MLB and the various programming distributors, perhaps this Committee could proceed strategically by threatening onerous legislation (barring collective sales of sports broadcasting rights to satellite and cable, mandating a la carte programming, authorizing FCC rate regulation of premium programming, etc.) unless the parties reach a voluntary agreement or agree to submit the matter to binding commercial arbitration.
 
Conclusion
 
    The MLB/DirecTV exclusive deal is not like a facially-similar contract between Sears and Levi’s.  Rather, the deal reflects (1) cartel behavior by MLB clubs in refusing to sell out-of-market rights to their games except via ExtraInningsTM on DirecTV and (2) a willingness of DirecTV to share the excess profits it enjoys from its Choice package with MLB.  Millions of baseball fans who no longer live near their favorite teams are harmed by their inability to watch their teams’ local broadcasts except via ExtraInningsTM, and harmed particularly by being forced to do so via DirecTV.  This Committee has a variety of arrows in its legislative quiver to protect consumers from this sort of exploitation.
 


RESTORING THE MARKET FOR OUT-OF-MARKET BASEBALL
Testimony of Professor Stephen F. Ross
Professor of Law, The Dickinson School of Law
Director, Penn State Institute for Sports Law, Policy and Research
The Pennsylvania State University
Before the
Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation
March 27, 2007
 
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
 
1) Although exclusive dealing agreements with retailers whom consumers can access for free can often be pro-competitive, the MLB/DirecTV deal threatens to harm a wide variety of consumers
 
  • Fans who, for other reasons, are unable or unwilling to switch to DirecTV
  • Fans who would prefer to get out-of-market games other than the entire ExtraInningsTM package
 
2) The agreement exploits significant departures from the free market
 
  • MLB clubs agree to only telecast games in assigned territories, contrary to a 50-year old antitrust precedent
  • MVPDs face insufficient competition, allowing them excess profits for their basic premium service
 
3) Economic analysis shows that ordinarily, DirecTV would want to re-sell ExtraInnings to its cable and satellite rivals at a high per-subscriber charge; the exclusive deal reflects a sharing of additional excess profits DirecTV will obtain by forcing consumers to switch to its Choice or higher premium packages
 
4) Although the conduct is arguably illegal under the antitrust laws, a number of obstacles render litigation inadequate to protect consumers
 
5) Congress could, alternatively, consider:
 
  • Regulatory legislation to outlaw specific sports programming practices that harm consumers
  • Amendments to the Sports Broadcasting Act to specifically outlaw anti-consumer practices
  • “Strategic” legislation onerous to the industry that would facilitate voluntary compliance


1 Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. 320 (1961).
2 Id. at 334.
3 Standard antitrust analysis properly focuses on whether a product or service faces competition from “reasonable substitutes” that will draw consumers if there is a small but significant increase in price or decrease in quality of the good or service in question.  Courts have generally found that major sports are sufficiently unique in consumers’ hearts – baseball is, after all, the National Pastime – that a small increase in the price of watching a favorite baseball team will not send enough fans to the library or to cricket websites to render the move unprofitable.  See, e.g., National Collegiate Athletic Ass'n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984) (college football is a market distinct from professional football or other forms of entertainment); International Boxing Club v. United States, 358 U.S. 242 (1959) (championship boxing is a market distinct from non-championship boxing).
 
            Likewise, the issue here concerns quality telecasts to be displayed on television sets of increasing size and clarity.  Although some fans may prefer the convenience of watching webcasts of out-of-market games on their computers, or others are willing to endure the significant reduction in picture quality when subscribing to mlb.com, these webcasts are not the sort of reasonable substitutes for ExtraInningsTM that either antitrust doctrine or public policy ought require.
4 United States v. National Football League, 116 F.Supp. 319 (E.D. Pa. 1953).
5 See, e.g., Pittsburgh Athletic Co. v. KQV Broad. Co., 24 F. Supp. 490 (W.D. Pa. 1938).
6 116 F.Supp. 319 (E.D. Pa. 1953).
7 National Collegiate Athletic Ass’n v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85 (1984).
8 Chicago Professional Sports Ltd. v. National Basketball Ass’n, 961 F.2d 667 (7th Cir. 1992).
9 Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1  (1979).
10 Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc. v. American Soc’y of Composers, Authors & Publishers, 620 F.2d 930 (2d Cir. 1980).
11 CBS v. Broadcast Music, 441 U.S. at 10-11, citing United States v. American Soc’y of Composers, Artists & Publishers, 1940-1943 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 56,104 (S.D.N.Y. 1941).
12 NCAA, 468 U.S. at 107.
13 There are at least two recent examples of this phenomenon.  In 1992, the English Premier League, having agreed to show 60 of its 380 matches exclusively on the BSkyB satellite, rejected BSkyB’s offer to show 90 matches for a 50% increase in fees.  At about the same time, the National Basketball Association succeeded in strictly limiting the very popular broadcasts of the Chicago Bulls featuring Michael Jordan, despite evidence that Bulls’ broadcasts had minimal effects in other markets, refusing to copy MLB’s practice of taxing superstation revenue.
14 David Harbord & Marco Ottaviani, “Contracts and Competition in the Pay-TV Market,” London Bus. School Dep’t of Economics Working Paper No. DP 2001/5, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=289334. 
15 This phenomenon is known to economists as “double marginalization.”  Suppose the profit-maximizing price for ExtraInningsTM is $160/year.  (Any increase in price reduces demand, unless a product is essential to life.  Thus, raising the price from $150 to $160 will cause some marginal consumers to discontinue patronage, but if the number is small enough, the increase is profitable.  If 100 consumers refuse to go along with the increase, this would cost MLB/DirecTV $15,000.  But if a 10,000 consumers are willing to pay $160, this is an additional $100,000.  At some point, the number of consumers discontinuing purchases outweighs the additional income, just short of that point is the profit-maximizing price.)  If MLB sold rights on a per-subscriber basis, they would want to fix the price at $160 minus DirecTV’s costs.   If these costs were $5/subscriber, MLB would set the rights sale at $155.  However, this would leave DirecTV with no excess profits.  DirecTV would rather get some excess profits, even at the expense of losing some customers.  So DirecTV would be likely to charge $170 or more, costing MLB some customers and some profit.  These problems are avoided by a lump-sum sale.
16 Harbord & Ottaviani, supra, at 8.    To the extent that there are strategic gains from raising rivals’ cost, the incentive to re-sell is even stronger. 
17 Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 771 (1984).
18
 When the Supreme Court last revisited the issue in Flood v. Kuhn, 407 U.S. 258 (1972), the Court explicitly rejected its original holding that baseball was not interstate commerce, instead re-affirming the exemption because of baseball’s “unique characteristics and needs” and Congress’ “positive inaction” in sustaining the judicial precedents.  It is clear that baseball has no unique characteristics and needs with regard to broadcasting, a fact Congress recognized by including baseball as a sport covered by the limited exemption for package sales to free-to-air networks contained in the Sports Broadcasting Act.  Congress’ positive inaction with regard to the baseball exemption, upon which Justice Blackmun relied in Flood, related almost entirely to labor restraints.  When Congress overturned that specific aspect of Flood in enacting the Curt Flood Act of 1995, it is clear that continuing legislative concern almost entirely related to protecting the unique characteristics and needs of minor league baseball, not broadcasting practices that MLB shares in common with the NBA and the NHL. 
 
            In addition, lower courts have suggested that the exemption applies only to the “business of baseball” and not to the “business of broadcasting.”  Henderson Broad. Corp. v. Houston Sports Ass'n, 541 F. Supp. 263 (S.D. Tex. 1982).  Especially in light of courts’ explicit recognition that MLB can lawfully require clubs to share revenues from rights sales, Chicago Professional Sports Ltd. Partnership, supra, 961 F.2d at 675, there is no reason why subjecting television agreements to standard antitrust analysis would compromise “the business of baseball.”
19 The current Supreme Court doctrine is expressed in Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984).  Firms engaged in a substantial amount of interstate commerce may not force consumers to purchase a product, service, or copyright license as a condition of purchasing a more desired license, where the seller has “market power,” the arrangement requires the purchase of two “separate products,” and the tying is not necessary to introduce a new product or to ensure the reliable use of either.  Applying this precedent, it is clear that DirecTV has market power in the sale of ExtraInningsTM, as there are no reasonable substitutes for out-of-market MLB games.  Forcing purchasers of ExtraInningsTM to purchase the Choice package constitutes a tied sale, because there is distinct and separate consumer demand for both products.  Finally, a there is no need to tie well-established programs in the Choice package with uniquely desirable MLB games in order to penetrate a market, and there are no reliability issues in subscribing to one or the other. 
20 See, e.g., Robert Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 365-381 (1978).
21 See, e.g., Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., 504 U.S. 451, 487 (Scalia, J., dissenting); Hyde, 466 U.S. at 32 (O’Connor, J., concurring).
22
 William Howard Taft, The Anti-Trust Act and the Supreme Court (1914).
23 Valley Liquors, Inc. v. Renfield Importers, Ltd., 678 F.2d 742, 745 (7th Cir. 1982).
24 This legislation would also prevent cable companies from aggressively competing in a consumer-harming way by acquiring their own exclusive sports programming rights and refusing to re-sell to satellite outlets.
 
            Another example, of perhaps little interest to most Americans but of keen interest to millions, especially recent immigrants from south Asia or the United Kingdom, concerns the rights to satellite broadcasting of international cricket matches.  Thus, DishNetwork obtained exclusive rights for the International Cricket Council’s World Cup contests currently being played in the West Indies, while DirecTV obtained exclusive rights to a large number of international contests throughout the year.  Devoted cricket fans need to either subscribe to both or forego the ability to watch these matches in their homes.
25 The substance of the agreement, and whether the agreement or proposed legislation accurately reflects the public interest in an appropriate balance between protecting (i) players’ health, (ii) the integrity of the game from health-harming, performance-enhancing behavior, and (iii) privacy rights, is of course beyond the scope of this testimony as well as my scholarly expertise.
 
 
Banner

Poll

Should MLB Force Jeffery Loria to Sell the Marlins?